Summary box
Developing a safe, effective COVID-19 vaccine alone will not be enough to end the
pandemic—the vaccine must also be delivered globally at a price affordable to all
governments and allocated in a way that maximises public health impact and achieves
equity.
These goals are being threatened as rich nations enter into bilateral purchase agreements
with COVID-19 vaccine manufacturers, potentially hoarding the global supply.
It is impossible to stop these bilateral deals—the best we can achieve is to find
ways to configure these deals to also benefit the new COVID-19 Vaccine Global Access
Facility (COVAX), which aims to guarantee equitable access to COVID-19 vaccines worldwide.
A game theory analysis suggested ways in which bilateral deals could potentially improve
the global supply of vaccines, for example, if the manufacturer involved in the deal
shares know-how or if the deal expands the global supply of critical inputs that might
otherwise constrain production of COVAX vaccines.
Introduction
Progress in developing COVID-19 vaccines has been rapid: the first clinical trial
of a vaccine candidate began in Seattle, USA on 16 March 2020—just 63 days after China
shared the genetic sequence of SARS-CoV-2, the virus that causes COVID-19. As of 12
November 2020, there were 48 candidate vaccines in clinical trials.1 Given standard
attrition rates, we can expect at least a handful of COVID-19 vaccines to eventually
be launched.
However, developing a safe, effective vaccine alone will not be enough to end the
pandemic. The vaccine must also be delivered globally at a price affordable to all
governments and allocated in a way that maximises immediate and long-term public health
impact and simultaneously achieves equity. In previous pandemics, these goals were
not achieved. For example, in the 2009 influenza A (H1N1) pandemic, rich countries
monopolised the vaccine supply; low-income countries (LICs) and middle-income countries
(MICs) received fewer doses much later in the pandemic.2
The international community could have learnt lessons from this debacle and put in
place a different kind of global vaccine allocation system for COVID-19. In an ideal
system, manufacturers would openly share patents and manufacturing technology and
adopt transparent, non-profit pricing; manufacturing would be globalised; and countries
worldwide would pool funding to buy and allocate vaccines for everyone who needs them,
free at the point of care. Unfortunately, we failed to learn from the H1N1 pandemic—rich
nations are again flexing their market power by entering into bilateral purchase agreements
with COVID-19 vaccine manufacturers (table 1), potentially hoarding the global supply.3
Such ‘vaccine nationalism’ is a major threat to reaching global herd immunity and
a return of normal social and economic activity.4 5
Table 1
Selected examples of bilateral COVID-19 vaccine purchasing agreements, as of November
12, 2020 (source: https://launchandscalefaster.org/COVID-19)
Purchaser (country)
Vaccine manufacturer
Number of doses committed by manufacturer to purchaser, millions
Total number of doses committed to purchaser, millions
USA
Oxford University
300
810
Janssen (J&J)
100
Moderna
100
Novavax
110
Pfizer
100
Sanofi-GSK
100
Canada
Novavax
76
358
Medicago
76
Sanofi-GSK
72
Moderna
56
Janssen (J&J)
38
Oxford University
20
Pfizer
20
UK
Oxford University
100
340
Novavax
60
Sanofi-GSK
60
Valneva
60
Janssen (J&J)
30
Pfizer
30
Japan
AstraZeneca
120
240
Pfizer
120
The COVID-19 Vaccine Global Access Facility (COVAX)
The new COVID-19 Vaccine Global Access Facility (COVAX)—led by Gavi, the Vaccine Alliance
(Gavi), the Coalition for Epidemic Preparedness Innovations (CEPI), and the WHO—attempts
to overcome vaccine nationalism. Acknowledging that bilateral deals cannot be prevented,
since rich nations will inevitably act in their self-interest, it encourages these
nations also to participate in COVAX to ‘guarantee rapid, fair and equitable access
to COVID-19 vaccines worldwide’.6
COVAX aims to deliver two billion doses of vaccine to vaccinate one billion people
(assuming a two-dose regimen) by the end of 2021 to participating countries. These
doses will come initially from CEPI, a public–private partnership that is financing
the development and initial manufacturing of a portfolio of COVID-19 vaccines (in
the future, COVAX will obtain vaccines from additional sources, not just CEPI). Available
doses of vaccines will be ‘allocated to all participating countries at the same rate,
proportional to their total population size’.7 The amount that countries receive should
be enough to at least vaccinate all of the highest priority populations (eg, health
workers and the elderly). About 5% of the facility’s vaccine supply will be held in
a reserve stockpile for deployment in acute outbreaks and humanitarian settings.6
7
There are two ways to participate in COVAX, depending on a country’s income status:
Wealthier countries (high-income countries (HICs) and upper MICs) can participate
as ‘self-financing’ countries. By joining COVAX, they commit to procure enough doses
from the facility to vaccinate 10%–50% of their populations and also make an upfront
payment to support vaccine development and manufacturing. The amount they pay is a
reflection of the number of doses they want. These upfront contributions will support
the facility to enter into agreements with vaccine manufacturers to secure future
vaccine doses for participating countries.7 The more wealthier countries that participate,
the more that the financial risks of investing in the development and manufacturing
of multiple vaccine candidates will be shared (known as ‘derisking’) and the more
doses that can eventually be purchased.
Less wealthy countries (lower MICs and LICs) can participate as ‘funded’ countries,
with their financial commitments covered by official development assistance (ODA).
Within COVAX, a financing mechanism called the COVAX Advanced Market Commitment (AMC)
will be used to raise funds, mostly ODA, to pay for vaccine supply to these funded
countries.
Gavi states that it will try its best to support COVAX self-financing participants
to choose a particular vaccine from the COVAX portfolio, even though it still remains
uncertain which vaccines will be available, when, and at what scale.8 Gavi is also
establishing a COVAX Exchange—a marketplace for both self-financing and funded countries—to
‘facilitate trading of allocations of vaccine for all participants’.8
If a wealthy country is already doing deals on its own to secure vaccine, often with
a manufacturer based in that country (eg, the US government with the US company Novavax—table
1), participating in COVAX could still be valuable as an insurance policy. If the
wealthy country’s bilateral deals fail to produce a safe and effective vaccine, but
the country has participated in the facility, it can still get enough doses from COVAX
to vaccinate 10%–50% of its population.
Whether COVAX succeeds or fails depends in large part on how many and which wealthier
nations agree to participate in the mechanism, and on whether bilateral deals end
up crowding out global vaccine supply. By 30 September 2020, 74 countries had signed
financially binding commitments.9 The USA has so far expressed no interest in COVAX.10
Meanwhile, ‘many countries including Britain, the U.S., France, Germany, and others
have directly negotiated their own deals with pharmaceutical companies to receive
billions of doses, meaning that the vast majority of the world’s vaccine supply next
year is already reserved’.11
Incentivising participation by wealthier nations in COVAX
Other than offering an insurance policy, are there other incentives that COVAX could
provide to increase the number of wealthier countries that participate? We used game
theory to address this question.
Game theory attempts to predict the behaviour of key actors in a particular setting,
where the ‘payoff to strategies chosen by individuals depends on the strategies adopted
by others in the population’.12 A game is any situation with multiple decision-makers
(‘players’) whose choices impact one another. Game theory analysis has been used to
address various global health challenges, such as in predicting (1) the prescribing
behaviour of physicians in the face of rising antimicrobial resistance13 14; (2) population
behaviour under voluntary vaccination policies for childhood diseases12; and (3) when
social distancing practices are most valuable during pandemics.15 16
In a game theory analysis, researchers first identify the strategic ecosystem of interest
(in this case, the landscape of COVID-19 vaccine development, manufacturing and deployment);
the relevant players and their objectives; players’ strategic options; third parties
capable of changing the game; and other factors such as the timing and observability
of moves. The game we focused on is the current situation in which there are currently
multiple vaccine candidates, yet no certainty as to which ones will be the safest
and most effective. In this context, there are many players whose choices impact one
another:
Self-financing countries, deciding whether or not to participate in COVAX and/or to
make bilateral deals with vaccine manufacturers.
Vaccine manufacturers, deciding whether (and when) to agree to commit capacity through
COVAX and/or to make bilateral deals with countries.
Gavi and other global health institutions capable of influencing the ‘rules of the
game’ directly (eg, through the specific rules of COVAX) and indirectly (eg, by articulating
principles and facilitating collective action).
We did not include funded countries in the analysis because while they are impacted
by the decisions of the players listed above, they have no control over the outcomes.
Their choices do not impact others since they are automatically enrolled into the
facility and their doses are fully funded.
In many ways, COVAX is attempting to address what the ecologist Garrett Hardin called
a ‘tragedy of the commons’.17 The commons is a shared resource that has value to everyone;
its overuse by one actor can reduce its value to all others. Hardin wrote: “Ruin is
the destination toward which all men rush, each pursuing his own best interest in
a society that believes in the freedom of the commons. Freedom in a commons brings
ruin to all.” With COVID-19 vaccines, a tragedy of the commons can arise if HICs and
upper MICs fail to support the COVAX Facility financially and/or if they make globally
irresponsible bilateral deals that secure doses for themselves but fail to expand
the global supply base. On the other hand, richer countries can promote the common
public good by financially supporting COVAX’s efforts to expand global vaccine supply
and access, and by making bilateral deals that increase capacity, promote knowledge
sharing and generate other positive spillovers.
Our game theory analysis articulates how COVAX can serve as a mechanism to promote
such a commons, not just by enabling collective action but also by shaping HICs and
upper MICs’ incentives to make bilateral deals that benefit the broader global effort
as well as themselves individually.
The detailed technical methods that we used to conduct our game theory analysis are
shown in the online supplemental appendix. A preprint of this analysis was previously
published online.18 Our analysis generated two key findings, on (1) the benefits of
fungibility and harmonisation of investments, and (2) the potential value of adopting
principles for bilateral deals that could promote global benefits. We discuss each
of these further below.
10.1136/bmjgh-2020-003627.supp1
Supplementary data
Fungibility of investments and supply-chain harmonisation
Our game theory analysis suggests that Gavi and COVAX could enhance the ‘value proposition’
that COVAX offers to wealthier countries—thus incentivising them to participate in
and fund the facility—by promoting fungibility and supply-chain harmonisation.
Everyone benefits when (1) COVAX investments to accelerate production of a specific
vaccine candidate can be quickly repurposed to accelerate production of another vaccine
(‘fungibility’), and (2) critical inputs, processes and data are standardised across
as many vaccine candidates and production facilities as possible (‘harmonisation’).
Gavi and CEPI have a number of options to increase fungibility and promote harmonisation,
not just for their own investments but also for those being made by individual countries
or coalitions of countries (eg, the EU) outside COVAX. Many of these steps are already
being taken, such as putting explicit repurposing clauses in COVAX contracts and standardising
vials and other downstream inputs. Such steps enhance the value proposition of COVAX
for wealthier countries, in at least three ways.
First, increasing the fungibility of COVAX investments increases the value of each
‘share’ of COVAX output. If investing in vaccine A allows one to accelerate production
of vaccine A or vaccine B, then if vaccine A fails, having a ‘share’ in that investment
gives a country accelerated access to vaccine B instead. In this way, fungibility
magnifies wealthier nations’ bang-for-the-buck from funding COVAX.
Second, increasing the fungibility of non-COVAX investments expands the potential
reach of CEPI vaccines (ie, the vaccines that will be included in the COVAX portfolio).
Imagine that vaccine X is outside of the CEPI portfolio and country X makes investments
to accelerate production of vaccine X. If vaccine X fails and the investments are
non-fungible, then country X loses all of its investment and the rest of the world
gets no value from that investment. By contrast, if vaccine X fails but the investments
can be repurposed to accelerate production of a CEPI vaccine, then CEPI and country
X will be able to strike a deal that enables the CEPI vaccine to be produced by country
X—with the output perhaps being split between country X and other nations through
COVAX. The prospect of cultivating alternative uses for their own investments also
gives wealthier nations more incentive to collaborate with COVAX.
Third, increasing harmonisation across the supply chain allows CEPI to deploy its
own resources strategically, to fill gaps in others’ supply chains. Countries that
use CEPI resources to produce doses more quickly could be required to allocate some
of those doses to poorer countries through COVAX. The prospect of a robust supply
of inputs gives wealthier nations more incentive to collaborate with COVAX, and to
adopt any standardisation (eg, vials, clinical data, regulatory procedures) that COVAX
proposes.
Adopting principles for bilateral deals
How a bilateral deal impacts the rest of the world depends on how it is structured.
This differential impact can be seen in the stark contrast between two of the bilateral
deals made recently by the US government: the agreement between AstraZeneca and the
Biomedical Advanced Research and Development Authority (BARDA) (the ‘BARDA deal’),
and the agreement between the US Department of Health and Human Services (HHS) and
Pfizer/BioNtech (the ‘HHS deal’).
The HHS deal secures 100 million doses of the Pfizer vaccine for the USA (with an
option to buy 500 million more doses), but makes no at-risk investment and hence does
little to support vaccine development or to expand the availability of doses. This
is a deal designed to benefit the USA and Pfizer, but no one else. By contrast, the
BARDA deal funds advanced clinical studies, vaccine manufacturing technology transfer,
process development and scaled-up manufacturing. This deal potentially benefits LICs
and lower MICs in several ways, by funding higher risk activities and by generating
vaccine products, processes and manufacturing capability that can then be broadly
shared. Knowledge gained and shared in this way could help expand and accelerate production
of the AstraZeneca vaccine for other markets, and perhaps also speed up production
of other similar vaccines. This is a deal designed to benefit the USA, AstraZeneca
and the rest of the world.
The wealthier countries supporting the COVAX Facility have an incentive to secure
bilateral deals of their own. There is no way to stop wealthier countries from pursuing
these deals, but COVAX can influence how such deals are made, so that more of these
deals are beneficial to the rest of the world (like the BARDA deal) and not simply
‘vaccine grabs’ that take doses away from everyone else (like the HHS deal).
Our game theory analysis identifies two basic ways in which COVAX can shape wealthier
countries’ incentives to make bilateral deals with positive spillovers for the rest
of the world.
First, drawing on insights from Elinor Ostrom’s Nobel prize-winning work on how to
support community self-enforcement of good-behaviour norms,19 COVAX can articulate
principles for how wealthier countries ought to structure their bilateral deals, and
then create transparency as to which countries are making ‘good’ bilateral deals.
Countries and leaders recognised for making good deals would rightly gain global prestige,
while those who fail to do so would shame themselves. Providing clear guidance on
how to structure bilateral deals for global benefit, and creating opportunities to
‘socially sanction’ those that choose not to do so, may be enough to incentivise many
countries to do so.
Second, COVAX can work with partner countries to create extra benefits that only those
who make ‘good deals’ are able to enjoy. For instance, suppose that a COVAX-supporting
country makes a bilateral deal with substantial at-risk investment that expands overall
production capacity. That country could then coordinate with COVAX to enhance the
supply-chain resiliency of that new capacity and/or share technical information to
enable that capacity to be quickly repurposed, if necessary, to produce a different
vaccine. Countries that selfishly refuse to support COVAX’s efforts would miss out
on these extra benefits and, in the end, hurt themselves as well.
The question now becomes, how should we define a ‘good deal’? The economic concepts
of ‘first best’ and ‘second best’ are useful in setting bounds on what we can hope
to achieve. In an ideal world, each country would devote most of its COVID-19 investment
dollars to the coordinated global effort—the ‘first best’. In the real world, each
country is captive to its own incentives. The ‘second best’ is the best we can achieve
subject to incentive constraints. In this case, rich nations that fund COVAX have
an incentive to also try to secure enough supplies for their entire population. The
fact that such investments could have helped the world even more if they had been
made within COVAX is irrelevant. The best we can hope for—the second-best—is to steer
countries toward making bilateral deals with positive spillovers for the rest of the
world.
What are the spillovers?
When a country makes a bilateral deal to accelerate production of doses to cover its
own population, how does that deal directly or indirectly impact other countries?
If vaccine availability were fixed, then vaccine distribution would be a ‘zero-sum
game’, with any deal that benefits richer countries necessarily harming LICs and lower
MICs. In that context, the race by the rich world to strike bilateral deals clearly
harms poorer nations, as (1) rich nations are able to secure the first supplies and
(2) the race reduces the effectiveness of the global pandemic response. But vaccine
availability is not fixed. The game that countries are playing is therefore not zero-sum,
and the investments that richer countries are making to help themselves may also help
poorer ones.
Four sorts of spillovers—three positive, one negative—are significant in the context
of COVAX.
Increased production flow (positive spillover). The bilateral deals that wealthier
nations are making for COVID-19 vaccines typically entail massive at-risk investments
to increase the quantity and accelerate the timing of vaccine availability. Such investments
benefit these wealthier nations, but could also benefit other countries by expanding
the global flow of vaccine production. For instance, suppose the USA were to make
massive investments that sped up by 6 months the availability of a US-based vaccine
with capacity to vaccinate 100 million people per month. The first batches would go
to Americans but, because there are fewer than 600 (6×100) million US citizens, doses
would start being exported before the vaccine would otherwise have been available.
Increased optionality (positive spillover). Bilateral deals could be a means of identifying
‘backup/pivot options’ for CEPI and non-CEPI vaccine production. For example, suppose
that an HIC that has chosen to fund and partner with COVAX also makes a bilateral
deal with a vaccine maker to stand up some vaccine production facility, to be ready
to accelerate production of that vaccine. Much of the work that goes into that preparatory
process (eg, generating knowledge products, sourcing raw materials, and establishing
supply chain systems) could then be shared with COVAX to ease efforts to build COVAX’s
own option to pivot to produce that vaccine. This sharing can occur: (1) if or when
a CEPI vaccine fails yet a similar vaccine produced through the bilateral deal succeeds,
and/or (2) to expand overall production through multiple supplying sites and partners.
Neither the HIC nor the vaccine maker in this scenario has any reason to object to
complementary production in a COVAX-funded manufacturing facility. Indeed, both would
benefit: the HIC, by speeding the global recovery (and hence helping its own economy),
and the vaccine maker, by reaching additional markets and taking advantage of the
COVAX AMC subsidy.
Increased knowledge (positive spillover). Bilateral deals that accelerate learning
about a vaccine candidate could benefit others—as long as the learning is shared—by
improving others’ decisions and speeding their ability to pursue producing and/or
using that vaccine themselves. For example, as experts in a COVAX-funded production
facility learn how to accelerate production of a new vaccine candidate, what they
learn could benefit COVAX partners seeking to produce another similar vaccine. This
could be especially important for newer vaccine production platforms, both because
more remains to be learnt about how to optimise production and because process and
data-sharing standards are less likely to be well established. At the same time, those
working with newer technologies have more incentive not to share details that could
make it easier for others to backward engineer their intellectual property. A trusted
third party such as COVAX could play an important intermediating role, to encourage
information sharing.
Tying up scarce inputs (negative spillover). If domestic production ties up a critical
input, then accelerating production for a rich country will slow down production for
the rest of the world, setting up a zero-sum game. Negative spillovers could also
arise if a country’s efforts to secure its own supply disrupt the global supply chain.
For instance, an unscrupulous country might try to buy up all of some input as a means
of pressuring others to supply them with early doses and/or induce some supplier in
the COVAX supply chain to dishonour its agreements and instead serve their own individual
interests.
Figure 1 summarises the spillovers and the potential associated principles described
above.
Figure 1
Investments by high-income countries to secure their own vaccine supplies: examples
of potential spillovers and possible associated principles. CEPI, Coalition for Epidemic
Preparedness Innovations.
What will well-intentioned wealthier countries be willing to do?
Articulating best practice principles for bilateral deals can influence how richer
nations craft such deals, to improve outcomes for lower MICs and LICs, but only if
richer countries can accommodate the principles in question without too much trouble
or cost. For instance, to maximise positive spillovers due to increased knowledge,
a principle might be that the manufacturer share COVAX-standardised technical and
clinical data. Similarly, to minimise any negative spillovers due to tying up scarce
resources, a principle could be that any bilateral deal include arrangements to expand
global supply of critical inputs that might otherwise constrain COVAX production.
Conclusion
The proliferation of bilateral deals between richer nations and COVID-19 vaccine manufacturers
is a major threat to ensuring global distribution of vaccines and to achieving herd
immunity at a global scale. Such deals cannot be stopped, but insights from a game
theory analysis suggest ways in which these deals could be configured to potentially
improve the global supply of vaccines, by increasing fungibility of investments, enhancing
supply-chain harmonisation and articulating principles for such deals.